One Nation, Under Time?
——Standardizing Time in the United States, 1752 and 1883
央视国际 (2005年02月11日 16:43)
by
Mark M. Smith
Carolina Distinguished Professor
Department of History
University of South Carolina, USA
Presented at the International
Conference,
“Calendars of Nation-States:
Studies of Traditional Festivals
and National Holidays,”
China Folklore Society and the
Beijing Folklore Museum
February 14-15, 2005
Beijing, China
Abstract: This paper describes the evolution of uniform time in
America in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries.
It examines the motivation behind—and reaction to—the reform of the
calendar in 1752 and the introduction of standard time zones in 1883.
It concludes by comparing the two events and offers deliberately
tentative remarks on what the comparison might tell us about a broadly construed
“American” experience with time.
Introduction
Every year, most Americans change their clocks twice: they put their
clocks back one hour in the autumn, forward one in the spring.
News sources dutifully remind the public of the impending shifts and
notwithstanding the inevitable instances of oversleeping and a few missed
connections the process works smoothly. The
efficiency of it all, the quick twiddling of watch hands, the clicking of
digital clocks back or forward an hour is so embedded in American culture that
many people remain only dimly aware why they “fall back” and “spring
forward.” Even fewer understand
that that their annual reconfigurations of clock time are rooted in much earlier
movements standardizing first the colonial American calendar in 1752 and then
the nation’s time zones in 1883. In
other words, standard time generally—calendrical and clock—has such an
assumed cultural authority in modern America that, to paraphrase Norbert Elias,
its origins are rarely interrogated.[i]
I offer this paper as something of a reminder of those origins.
The paper investigates two moments in American history in an effort to
understand more broadly the “American” experience with standard time, at
least prior to the twentieth century. The
first moment occurred in the year 1752 when colonial North America adopted the
Gregorian calendar; the second was in 1883 when standard time zones were
instituted in the United States. The
paper considers the role played by the state in each episode, evaluates the
importance of commerce and science in each instance, and examines the impact of
standardized time on American temporal sensibilities generally.
1752: Calendar Reform in Colonial
America
The Event
By the mid-eighteenth century, there were two operational calendars in
Europe separated by eleven days and each beginning the year on different days.
The Gregorian calendar, instituted by Papal Bull in 1581/2, corrected the
inaccuracies of the Julian calendar and, by 1752, prevailed in many Catholic and
a few Protestant European states. Several
Protestant countries, however, held out against converting to a Catholic
calendar for religious reasons. As
a result, such countries—most notably Britain—not only began the year on a
different day (March 25 rather than January 1) but operated on a calendar that
was eleven days out of step with the Catholic one by the mid-eighteenth century.[ii]
The British calendar was reformed by Parliament in 1751 with an “Act
for Regulating the Commencement of the Year; and for Correcting the Calendar now
in Use.” It applied to Great
Britain and it colonies, North America included.
As Robert Poole explains in his astute examination of the reform in
Britain: “Wednesday 2 September was followed by Thursday 14 September. The
basic principle was that all events fixed to a particular date stayed on that
date, while the calendar itself was pulled forward eleven days.”
Financial transactions were supposed to run their full natural terms and
the start of the civil year was changed from March 25 to January 1, thus ending
the need to double date the year for the intervening days.[iii]
The Cause
Commercial and scientific concerns led the British government to adopt
the reform of the calendar. In
addition to the decline in anti-Catholicism that allowed for the political
adoption of an ostensibly “Catholic,” Gregorian calendar, the rise in
scientific rationalism, broadly construed, was an important force behind the
reform in both Britain and the colonies. The
Reverend Hugh Jones of Maryland, for example, seven years before the actual
reform penned a piece in the Gentleman’s Magazine calling for a
thorough standardization of weights, measures, and times to counter an “absurd
and unstable” calendar. Others
complained that the calendar was both practically and philosophically out of
sync with the spirit of an age. Astronomy,
scientific observation, enlightened inquiry, even the scientific study of the
human past, all were inconvenienced and muddled by the existence of two
calendars, one of which (the Julian) was so inaccurate that not reforming it
amounted to sentimentality trumping science and progress.[iv]
Commercial concerns on both sides of the Atlantic were also important in
generating support for the reform. For
years, merchants had to rely on both the Gregorian and the Julian calendar.
Colonial merchants had to know which countries, even which individual ports,
used which calendar. In 1670 they could read: “At Hamborough and
Strasburgh in Germany they do write the same stile with us here in England,
namely old stile; but in all other parts beyond the Seas (except New England,
Barbadoes, and where our English plantations are) they do generally write new
stile.” The source of this wisdom is John Marius’s seventeenth-century
treatise, Advice Concerning Bills of Exchange, which continued to be
reissued until 1794. Anglo-American merchants made good use of this handy guide,
which contained information on when bills of exchange fell due in old and new
style. Malachy Postlethwayt thought the question of calendars and their
relevance to merchants sufficiently important to include in the 1774
edition of his Universal Dictionary of Trade and Commerce. He also
reminded English and American merchants, now that their calendar was reformed,
that they had to remain vigilant in their dealings with countries that were
still on the old style. “All merchants, bankers, and traders,” he
advised, “who deal with such Protestants as have not yet admitted the new
calendar, ought to be acquainted with that difference, because of the days
on which their bills of exchange become due.”[v]
Pre-calendar-reform America, then, was very much in tune with the new
style, not least because it was the one used by maritime interests throughout
the colonial period. Transatlantic sailors relied on calendars and almanacs that
contained both styles of dating, and transatlantic merchants were familiar
with both styles primarily because their international dealings mandated their
competency with both systems. But
familiarity didn’t mean convenience. Not
only might missing payments by more than the three days’ customary grace mean
money lost on interest and attendant penalties but the “punctual paying [of]
Bills, and thereby maintaining Credit” was essential for merchants’
reputations. “Nothing,” commented Daniel Defoe in his Complete English
Tradesman (1726), “can be of more moment to a Tradesman, than to pay [a
bill] always punctually and honourably.” Unsurprisingly, then, some of the
earliest calls for reform of the English calendar touted the commercial
advantage. Switching to new style, it was argued in 1656, will “much
facilitate commerce with Forren Nations, and cut off the duple difference
of Stilo veteri & novo, which makes much confusion in letters, accompts, and
transactions among Merchants.” American merchants agreed. The innovation, it
was maintained, “will be of great convenience to merchants, &c.
corresponding with other nations, who have generally received this
correction of the calendar, (commonly called New Stile) and tend to prevent
disputes about the dates of letters, accounts, &c.” In retrospect, the
“new stile” was “doubtless the justest” despite its papal origins.
“Our grand concern,” observed English historian Adam Anderson in 1801, “in
a mercantile sense, was to reduce our stile to uniformity with the rest of
Europe; the difference of days frequently occasioning errors and mistakes in
business.”[vi]
Given these imperatives, colonial merchants responded to the 1752
recalibration with ease and relief. Merchants
throughout colonial North America welcomed the reform. The dual calendar had
been an inconvenience for them and the evidence suggests that they were anxious
to be “freed from the confusion” of what a Boston newspaper described at the
time of the reform as the “absurd” dual calendar. Merchants, the Virginia
Gazette reported in 1751, were keen to adopt an international calendar that
would be “agreeable to that of other Nations.”[vii]
The new calendar, in short, rendered transatlantic trade more stable,
predictable, and efficient.
The Effect
According to Robert Poole, the English response to the calendar shift had
an ideological aspect. It was the
gentry, the reformers of the calendar, Poole argues, who injected ideology to
the debate because in their response to the war with revolutionary France and
its decimal ‘calendar of reason,’ the English aristocracy nostalgically
resurrected old style Julian festivals at the end of the eighteenth century.[viii]
By contrast, American colonists dealt with the reform rather more
efficiently and reliably. Certainly, ideology had less purchase in the American context
than in the British one, thus suggesting that Daniel Boorstin’s
characterization of colonial Americans as a particularly pragmatic people might
not be without at least some foundation.[ix]
Colonial newspapers in all regions, for example, disseminated news of the
impending shift effectively and widely, often reprinting the Act in full, and a
variety of almanacs offered commentary on how, exactly, the Act would work.
Some colonial assemblies even used public money to disseminate news of
the new public time. Connecticut, for example, paid “Mr. Timothy Green,
printer, the sum of ninety-four pounds six shillings . . . for printing the act
of Parliament for altering the stile and correcting the calendar, and finding
paper, &c., for the same.” As
a result, the implementation of the new style was accompanied with little
fanfare, problem, or frustration.[x]
The evidence here is tricky not least because ascertaining if people made
the shift efficiently is to some extent contingent on whether or not they
omitted (correctly), reference to September 3-13 in their dairies and other
documents. But we do know that
colonists were critical of public sources that got it wrong. On September 14,
1752, John Draper, proprietor of the Boston News-Letter, published
the following notice from Nathaniel Ames of Dedham, Massachusetts: “As the
New-Stile commences to-Morrow, and my Almanack 1752, is not conformable
thereto, and mention is made in the last Monday’s Evening Post of my being
wrong; I beg leave to make the following Apology, and desire you would make the
same Publick by inserting it in your paper on that Day, being the I4th Day of
September 1752, N. S.” Ames explained: “Now, as my Almanack goes on in the
common Way, and does not conform to [the Act], I was in hopes my Readers would
have been satisfy’d with what I offer’d them in said Almanack, Namely
That when the Copy was sent to the Press, I had no certain Account of the said
Act of Parliament:—It would have been a great Error in me indeed to have left
out the Eleven Days of the common Calendar at any other Time than exactly where
the said Act of Parliament had ordered . . . and it was not possible for me to
conform to a Law that I had never seen, and so could not understand.”[xi]
Such oversights were unusual. Not
only did most people understand and abide by the provisions of the Act but
American colonists were quite sensitive to oversights contained in the original
Act’s provisions. Because the British Parliament was apparently ignorant
of the timing of colonial North American law courts, assemblies had to be vigilant
to the change. In the May session of 1752, the Massachusetts Assembly, realizing
that court times in Worcester and Hampshire Counties were scheduled to be
held during the deleted eleven days, altered the times in advance: “Whereas by
Reason of there being but nineteen Days in the Month of September next, the
Superior Court of Judicature Court of Assize and General Gaol Delivery, cannot
this Year be held in and for the County of Hampshire, at the Time by Law
appointed for holding the same, nor can the said Court this Year be holden in
and for the County of Worcester at the Time by Law appointed for holding the
same.”[xii]
If colonial Americans accommodated the reform with apparent ease, they
also distinguished themselves from the British elite by not holding onto old
style festivals after the calendar had been reformed.
Few people in colonial America clung to old-style, Julian festivals or
dates. Yes, a few individuals
continued to celebrate their birthdays according to the old style—most notably
George Washington and John Adams—and a few people celebrated Christmas old
style in Virginia in the 1770s. But
even in these instances, they also observed Christmas Day new style—December
25—and it seems that the celebration of birthdays on old style days did not
preclude a recognition that the same day also had its new style equivalent.
John Adams certainly noted both days and seems to have regarded his
old-style birthday as a sort of sentimental attachment.
Either way, old-style dating was doomed to evaporate.
As the generation born before 1752 began to die, there would be no one
left who had been born on an old-style day.
Moreover, it seems highly unlikely that Washington, Adams, or anyone else
who simply noted their old style birthdays stuck to the old, Julian calendar for
organizing other aspects of their lives or that they began the year on March 25
instead of January 1. By the end of
the eighteenth century, and probably well before, the 1752 reform of the
calendar had become so entrenched that few people remembered, let alone used,
the old style calendar.[xiii]
In short, there was no significant ideological, religious, or political
objection to—or legacy from—the reform of the calendar in colonial America.
Why did colonial Americans accommodate the change with less ideological
protest than their English counterparts? Commercial
and scientific factors on both sides of the Atlantic, as we have seen, were
important in pushing the Crown to reform the calendar.
In this sense, both American and British merchants and fans of
Enlightenment rationalism benefited from the reform and were probably equally
accommodating to it. What made
colonists in North America unusually pragmatic in accommodating the reform was a
preexisting cultural diversity that meant than colonial Americans had a temporal
competency and calendrical fluency long before the official reform of the
calendar. In other words, the peculiar immigrant make-up of colonial
America was important in shaping reaction to the reform of the calendar.
Perhaps as many as one-fifth of colonial Americans in 1752 was already
using the Gregorian system and had been doing so for years, long before the 1752
Act of Parliament came into effect. Because
colonial North America was home to immigrants from countries where the Gregorian
calendar had already been adopted, certain constituencies used the British,
Julian calendar and the Gregorian system prior to the 1752 reform.
Recall that France, Portugal, Spain and parts of the Netherlands, for
example, had adopted the Gregorian system at the outset, in 1582; various German
states—Protestant as well as Catholic—adopted the Gregorian calendar between
1584 and 1699. Thus, immigrants
from these and other “Gregorian” regions celebrated various cultural and
religious festivals and events (such as Christmas) according to a Gregorian
calendar even as they used the Julian one in their dealings with British
authorities.[xiv]
Although there was a regional dynamic to this practice—the middle
colonies were home to a wider mix of Europeans than, say, were the New England
colonies—the pattern of cultural retention of Gregorian time and simultaneous
use of the Julian system in official business prevailed everywhere.
Dutch settlers in Virginia, for example, recorded the birth of their
children by Gregorian style prior to the reform and Moravian travelers
throughout colonial America seemed to have used Gregorian style dating in their
own communities and only employed the Julian calendar when dealing with British
officials or groups of old-style Protestants.
Even slaves who had been exposed to the Catholic teachings of the
Portuguese in the Kongo in the fifteenth century arrived in the southern
colonies with their Catholic, Gregorian calendar intact.
Evidence suggests that a group of Kongolese-born slaves at Stono, South
Carolina initiated the largest servile revolt in colonial American history
according to their memories of their Catholic, Gregorian calendar.
They revolted on September 8, 1739, Mary’s nativity, new style.[xv]
A good illustration of this temporal fluency can be found in the
activities of the Salzburgers who left Augsburg in 1733 using the new style,
abandoned it in favor of the Julian calendar en route in London,
and kept it once they arrived in Julian-style Georgia. Even
as the German settlers formally abandoned the improved system, they periodically
reverted to it, especially when writing to friends and religious
authorities in Halle. Johann Martin Boltzius, for example, wrote to Gotthilf
August Francke, the Salzburgers’ spiritual leader, from Dover, England, on
December 19, 1733, new style, at the same time he began to employ Julian dating.
When in Georgia, Boltzius and Israel Christian Gronau were careful to narrate
their experiences to colleagues in Halle by indicating which style they were
using in their letters. From Ebenezer, “Mr. Zwifler, the Apothecary,” wrote
to friends in Augsburg on “the 14th of May (new style), 1734.” Salzburger
settlers did not forget their Gregorian calendar and used both old and new
style depending on constituency. The new calendar was simply too braided with
their religious identity and cultural memory to abandon wholly. As Boltzius and
Gronau wrote from England, en route to Georgia: “We remembered that Christmas
was being celebrated in Germany at this time, which moved us to heartfelt
prayer.”[xvi]
On the whole, then, the reform of the calendar in colonial America
suggests the importance of scientific and commercial forces behind the 1752 Act
and the relevance of calendrical time to cultural identity.
Moreover, many colonial Americans had a temporal competency that was
actually in advance of the British state in 1752 because they were already using
the “new” style in an “old” style context.
The peculiar and particular cultural makeup of colonial America ensured
that the colonial experience with calendar reform less contested than the
British one. In other words,
cultural heterogeneity in colonial America gave rise to a temporal competence
and pragmatism largely missing from the more ideological charged British
experience. And the irony here is
obvious: although the reform of the calendar did not cause Americans to revolt
against Britain, it did allow for them to help form an imagined community by
using common dates and to coordinate reliably during the Revolutionary War.[xvii]
1883: From Days to Hours
The Event
One hundred and thirty one years after the reform of the calendar,
Americans made another, incremental move towards uniform time. On November 18,
1883 American cities, towns, and villages abandoned forty-nine local or
sun-regulated times in favor of four scientific, clock-defined time zones. The
telegraph, not the sun, now communicated time to a temporally unified nation.
This “day of two noons” was also the day of one nation. By the end of
1883, there was no longer any such thing as local or regional time. In both a literal and figurative sense, the longitudinal time
zones now bracing the nation had replaced the sectional, political, latitudinal
lines that had served to separate the country during a previous generation.
The Cause
Although historians disagree on who exactly was responsible for the introduction
of standard time, it is clear that both the scientific community and railroad
interests had long considered the need for a system of uniform and standard time
in their vast and sprawling country. As early as 1809, amateur astronomer
William Lambert recommended to Congress the establishment of time meridians in
the United States but got nowhere not least because the immediate benefit of
such ordered time wasn’t immediately obvious in a country that had yet to
experience much of an industrial or, indeed, market revolution.
As Carlene Stephens has rightly observed, “Local time was sufficient
when people and goods traveled slowly, infrequently, and over short
distances.”[xviii]
The coming of the railroads in the 1830s changed this.
Railroads and, later, telegraphs, had the effect of reducing American
space and, in the process, highlighting the temporal variations between
communities. The idea of a
standard, albeit localized, time was considered as early as 1834 by the engineer
of the South Carolina Canal and Railroad Company in an effort to carry mail with
greater reliability and so avoid stiff financial penalties imposed by the Post
Office for late deliveries. As a
result, the railroad placed six clocks at various depots along its 136-mile
track in a bid to standardize running time and avoid the confusion of passing
through lots of local “zones.” By
all accounts, the new system worked and the Charleston and Hamburg became
increasingly punctual, reliable, and, importantly, profitable.[xix]
Other railroad companies faced different problems but used similar
solutions. In New England, two
spectacular train crashes in August, 1853, led to a heightened sensitivity to
the need for train scheduling and efforts to establish local standard time. The
crash on the Providence & Worcester Railroad on August 12, 1853, in which
fourteen people died courtesy of the conductor’s faulty watch, led railroad
officials to begin using precision timepieces at all their stations and issue a
set of precise guidelines detailing “Standard Time” on the railroad.[xx]
In addition, as Ian Bartky has shown, “astronomers, many of whose
observatories provided time to the railroads,” via telegraph signals,
also “began to write about uniform time in the early 1870s.” The combined
forces of the need for a uniform time system in the fields of geophysics,
surveying, and, especially after the completion of the transcontinental railroad
in 1869, railroading, slowly pushed the United States toward the adoption
of standard time in 1883. Following
Charles F. Dowd’s lead, in the 1870s at least four North American scientific
societies began discussing the desirability of standard time zones.
The American Metrological Society, the American Association for the
Advancement of Science, the American Society of Civil Engineers, and the
Canadian Institute all formed committees on standard time and disseminated
information on the matter to the general public. At first, railroads were not
especially welcoming of the move. They considered the scientists impractical,
outsiders, and idealistic and thought that people simply wouldn’t embrace
standard time zones because most of them were not long distance travelers.
But, gradually, the scientists won the day.
Yale University astronomer Leonard Waldo managed to convince the state of
Connecticut to abolish the five different railroad times in his state on the
grounds of economic efficiency, scientific reasoning, and pubic safety.
Within the federal government, Cleveland Abbe of the U.S Weather Bureau
pushed for—and won—the hosting of an international conference on standard
time and in 1884 that meeting took place in Washington, D.C.[xxi]
Standard Time in the U.S. was, then, inspired by science and commerce.
In many ways, the man responsible for drafting the specifics of Standard
Time embodied both interests. William
F. Allen had been a railway engineer in New Jersey and was later instrumental in
constructing various railroad timetables. Allen
spoke at the General Time Convention in St. Louis in April, 1883, urged the
adoption of Standard Time, and inaugurated a public relations campaign, one
supported by most railroads, businesses, and scientists, to effect new time
zones. It worked and on November
18, 1883, Allen’s time zones were established.
Drawing on several previous plans, Allen proposed a map dividing the
country into four zones, each exactly fifteen degrees of longitude, or one hour,
apart. This division ignored state geopolitical boundaries and the existing
patchwork time divisions established by individual railroad companies.
“Practicality,” as Michael O’Malley writes, “ruled the minds of
railroaders, and they felt no sentimental or patriotic attachment to the time of
one particular city . . . What they wanted most was a plan that altered existing
division breaks, and the accustomed day to day operations of the roads, as
little as possible.” They got it.
From atop the Western Union Building in New York City, Allen observed the
changeover with justified pride: “Standing on the roof of that building . . .
I heard the bells of St. Paul’s strike on the old time. Four minutes later,
obedient to the electrical signal from the Naval Observatory . . . the time-ball
made its rapid descent, the chimes of old Trinity rang twelve measured strokes,
and local time was abandoned . . ..”[xxii]
The Effect
The new standard time required railroads and, by implication, everyone
who used the train, to advance or retard their clocks and watches so many
minutes, according to the zone in which their locality lay. The zoning required
people in New Orleans, Denver, and Philadelphia to do nothing. Those in New York
City, however, had to stop their clocks four minutes; people in Washington, D.C.
advanced theirs eight minutes, while Chicagoans retarded theirs nine
minutes. What amounted to a revolution in time was, for most people, a matter of
adjusting clocks and watches a few minutes. Jewelers, train station and post
office clocks, and public town clocks, once local, civic authorities had
assented to the change, quickly adopted the new time and provided the source for
people to set their watches to standard time.
Even more than the reform of the calendar in 1752—which required state
actualization and implementation of recommendations originating in part from
commercial and scientific communities—the institution of standard time in
1883 was a largely non-government-instigated reform. It was not until 1918 that
the federal government began to legislate civil time. Indeed, the option for
communities to adhere to local time continued until 1967, when federal
legislation finally preempted all civil time statutes. “Even today,” as one
historian has pointed out, “the United States’ civil-time system is not
uniform: About 3 percent of the population lives in areas that do not observe
daylight saving time.” Revealingly, Washington, D.C., was one of the last
places legally to adopt, by an act of Congress, standard time. The capital’s
attorney general, Benjamin Brewster, was unsure of the constitutionality of
standard time in the District and so ordered government offices not to adopt the
new time until Congress authorized them to do so. It did so in March 1884.
In some instances, the state played catch-up to the market in the
standardization of time in the United States.[xxiii]
State mandate or no, some people after 1883 (and throughout the twentieth
century, in fact) clung to different times.
Following November 18, 1883, some clergymen, for example, argued that
their local time was immune to molestation by private, Mammon-worshiping
railroad interests because their time was God’s. Still others resisted the new
time precisely because they thought it was introduced by the railroads. As
the Indianapolis Daily Sentinel put it three days after the introduction
of the new time, “The sun is no longer to boss the job. People . . . must eat,
sleep and work . . . by railroad time . ... People will have to marry by
railroad time.” In an age distrustful of railroad conglomerates, railroad time
lacked the legitimacy that local time and all its affiliations with God and
nature bestowed.
Yet such objections were the exception. Ministers in New York,
Philadelphia, and Chicago did not denounce the new time and outside of Indiana,
where distrust of the railroads was strong, few public complaints against the
new “railroad time” were made. Nor
did opposition to the new time devolve on a rural-urban or a North-South axis.
While the very largest cities like Chicago and New York made the transition to
standardized clock time smoothly, there was considerable resistance to the
abandonment of sidereal time in such urban centers as Boston, especially from
the working poor. Some citizens in Bangor, Maine, Detroit, Michigan, and
throughout Ohio also initially refused to accept the new time.
A similar ambivalence prevailed in the South. While the Atlanta
Constitution applauded “the utter contempt into which the sun and moon
have fallen,” thus allowing “progress into the future,” southern
“country folks continued to set their clocks by the sun” and insisted
on sidereal time.[xxiv]
Opposition to the new time had little to do with culture and more to do
with convenience. In fact, those who resisted did so using terms similar to
those employed by commercial interests and scientists who had originally pushed
for the new zones. For example,
resistance to standard time was strongest in those localities concentrated in
the eastern regions of the two most eastern time zones where the shift disrupted
civic and business schedules. Although Allen had predicted that the
standardization of time would cause a variation between local and standard time
of no more than thirty minutes, the new eastern zone’s standard time actually
caused a discrepancy between the old, local time and the new national time
ranging from thirty-two minutes on the zone’s eastern edge to thirty-eight
minutes on its western. Similarly, in the adjacent central time zone, the
discrepancy between standard and local time ranged between forty-five and
sixty-six minutes. The net effect for people at the extreme of these zones was a
perceived and real change, either a reduction or increase in the amount of
sunlight.
Places at the extremes resisted standard time and opted to use the zone
most convenient for their locality. Augusta, Georgia, which lay on the border of
two zones, for example, did not adopt eastern time until 1888. Cincinnati, on
the central time zone border, refused to put the city clocks back twenty-two
minutes, as did Dayton, Ohio, Detroit, Michigan, and several other states and
cities located along the zones’ borders. Between 1883 and 1915 standard time
came to trial before the supreme courts of various states at least fifteen
times. Supreme courts in Nebraska (1890) and Kentucky (1905) and the Texas
Circuit Court in 1895 all ruled that although the uniform time had been adopted
in many places, local time still ruled legally.[xxv]
And yet in the majority of places—locations that had to adjust their
times by only a few minutes, those not on the borders of time zones—there was
ready acceptance of the zones. The newspapers in New Orleans, Atlanta, and
Little Rock, Arkansas, for example, explained in sober and practical terms the
reasons for the change and the impact it would have.
Even in small towns where the adjustment was quite significant, the
perceived need for standardization seems to have won people over. Rugby’s Plateau
Gazette and East Tennessee News simply informed its readers: “Last Sunday
the time on all the railroads were [sic] changed to the new ‘Standard Time,’
which will make our time 22 minutes slower.” The relatively substantial loss
elicited little comment. And Louisville’s Courier-Journal similarly
argued that “the adoption of the new railway standard in this country can be
accomplished without much difficulty by all communities; otherwise there will be
misunderstanding about local and standard time which will continue to befog
travellers.” Or, as one small
South Carolina newspaper editor put it: “The Change is a good thing and will
be a great convenience to the travelling public.” On the whole, the changeover went smoothly with little
opposition.[xxvi]
Conclusion
Comparison of historical events removed in time by a hundred and thirty
odd years is fraught with danger and the temptation to see genuine similarity
where there is only accidental, happy coincidence is great.
A careful evaluation, though, suggests quite clearly that the two
episodes in the evolution of standard time in American history share some
fundamental similarities.
Both the 1752 reform and the 1883 zoning were inspired by similar
constituencies. In both instances
the scientific community lobbied for a rationalized time system and expressed
concern and contempt for prevailing, multiple, confusing temporal systems. Commercial interests also played an important role on both
occasions in lobbying for the reform and for similar reasons: unreformed
calendars and time systems created uncertainty, courted mistakes, and generally
proved aggravating for merchants and businesses anxious to both protect a bottom
line and streamline operations.
In both 1752 and 1883 the state played a limited and modest role in
initiating temporal reform. Plainly,
the British Parliament was important for debating the matter in 1752 and for
passing the specific legislation. But
the deeper forces behind the reform were scientists, individuals interested in
Enlightenment balance and perspective, and commercial interests, less so
politicians. In 1883, the role of
the federal government was even less pronounced.
Again, the American state facilitated the implementation of standard time
but long after the 1883 event (not until 1918) and its instigative role was
relatively modest.
I do not wish to minimize the extent and nature of disputes over time
evident just after each reform, and, in fact, in the period after 1883.
Between 1752 and 1883, in fact, there were contests over time, its
meaning, its value, and its religious and cultural worth throughout the United
States, contests that helped educate Americans generally on the nature of time.
Because time was so tightly indexed to religious meaning, work, freedom,
patriotism, and character, debates over time were virtually inevitable.
The Revolution, for example, had created a citizenry whose virtue was
gauged by punctuality, especially in business.
In the antebellum North, industrialization helped sharpen a preexisting,
if vague, commitment to clock time and by the 1830s, factories were regulated by
clock time. Initially, managers
aimed simply to make workers obedient to the factory’s time which was
communicated aurally through the use of clock-regulated bells and whistles.
But workers recognized that managers manipulated work time by altering
the hands of the factory clock. Bosses,
workers realized, “start up the mills several minutes, sometimes seven, eight,
nine, or ten minutes, before the time for commencing work,” thereby stealing
both their time and labor. Factory
operatives, therefore, bought ever less expensive watches for themselves in an
attempt to combat managers’ definitions of when work really began and ended.
The debate over true time was very much to do with not only who owned
time but who defined it, and managers and workers both appealed to the apparent
objectivity of the mechanical timepiece to stake their claims.[xxvii]
Then there was the vigorous debate about the meaning and worth of Sunday.
A variety of Protestant churches in the antebellum period lobbied hard
for social fidelity to the fourth commandment: “the seventh day is the Sabbath
of the Lord thy God.” These “Sabbatarians” worked to keep Sunday pure because
they saw commercial forces making in-roads on the sanctity of God’s time on
the Sabbath. Their determination to
keep Sunday as a day of rest—to protect God’s time from commercial
time—took various forms. Sabbatarians
tried to prevent the opening of post offices, libraries, museums, and theatres
on Sundays; attempted to prevent railroads and steamboats from running; and
argued against the sale of newspapers on God’s day.
To this day, something of the Sabbatarian impulse lingers in the form of
various blue laws, especially in the American South, which prohibit the sale of
alcohol.[xxviii]
Neither were contests over time unknown in the twentieth century.
Daylight saving time, for example, has its origins in World War I when
business interests argued that an extra hour of sun light would not only
increase American industrial efficiency but would allow citizens extra time to
pursue leisure interests. Some balked at the proposal, notably farmers, who benefited
from more light in the morning. But
the industrialists won the day not least because getting people to work earlier
appealed to the patriotic need for increased efficiency during the War.
“If I have more Daylight I can work longer for my country,”
maintained reformers. Perhaps inevitably, some people still refuse to abide by
standard or clock time. Although
daylight saving time has been federal law since 1918, parts of Arizona and
Indiana still refuse to adopt it. Some
religions eschew mechanical time by praying at sunrise, noon, and sunset.
And for those who remain peripheral to America’s market economy, such
as the homeless, clock time has only fleeting relevance to their lives.
But too much is sometimes made of these
“hold outs,” the people who refuse to accept temporal reforms or who operate
according to times supposedly erased. I
suspect we exaggerate either the numbers who “resist” in this way and I
think we are sometimes prone to exaggerate the political significance and
meaning of such resistance. Even though time is still contested and contingent,
as it always has been, most people accept the clock, national calendars, and
time zones sometimes as a necessary evil, often as a positive good.
Moreover, the debates themselves over the meaning and nature of time that
took place between 1752 and 1883 likely helped sharpen popular appreciation of
time and temporal orders and made the 1883 reconfiguration understandable and
relatively trouble-free. Indeed,
even those who resist daylight saving time or other forms of standard time often
do so because the mandated temporal system simply isn’t as efficient or as
convenient—as socially or economically functional—as their alternative time
system.
On the whole, a standard calendar and standard time work because similar
commercial and scientific imperatives that gave rise to the temporal reform in
the first place still have enormous currency in the United States. Moreover, people have proven adaptable when accommodating to
standard time generally. Neither
1752 nor 1883 profoundly challenged the basic meaning people attached to their
affective, cultural times not least because the temporal and cultural plurality
of the American experience meant that people had been used to existing in
multiple times while also recognizing the functional importance and desirability
of a single calendar or standard time system.
The American experience with multiple temporal regimens allowed for the
adoption of new standardized times and the quiet retention of other, additional
cultural time-systems. This does
not mean to say that all Americans always willingly surrendered cultural
temporal systems in the face of the introduction of standard time systems.
But the American experience—if we might talk so broadly—does suggest
that a pragmatic sensibility leads to relatively ready acceptance of
standardized time and that standard time itself is a basic component of the
cultural understanding of time in the United States.
Americans have proven adept at retaining cultural times important to
their specific constituency, abandoning regimens that seem outdated, and
embracing ones that serve commonsensical social and economic functions.
Perhaps this willingness to discriminate, adapt, and evolve is itself an
avenue for better understanding the slippery, multiple, “American” national
character.
NOTES
[i]
Norbert Elias, Time: An Essay, trans. Edmund Jephcott (Cambridge,
Mass., 1992), p.6.
[ii]
See G. V. Coyne, M. A. Hoskin, and O. Pedersen, eds., Gregorian Reform of
the Calendar: Proceedings of the Vatican Conference to Commemorate Its 400th
Anniversary, 1582-1982 (Vatican City, 1983); Paul Alkon, “Changing the
Calendar,” Eighteenth-Century Life, 7 (1981-82), pp.1-18.
[iii]
Robert Poole, “‘Give Us Our Eleven Days!’: Calendar Reform in
Eighteenth-Century England,” Past and Present, 149 (1995),
pp.95-139.
[iv]
See, for example, Gentleman’s Magazine, 15 (1745), pp.377-79;
Urbanus Sylvan, Gentleman’s Magazine, 5, (1735).
See also John Davenport Neville, “Hugh Jones and his Universal
Gregorian Calendar,” Virginia Cavalcade, 26 (1977), pp. 134-143;
David S. Landes, Revolution in Time: Clocks and the Making of the Modern
World (Cambridge, Mass., 1983), pp.146-164.
[v]
Mark M. Smith, “Culture, Commerce, and Calendar Reform,” William and
Mary Quarterly, 3rd ser., LV (October 1998), p.577.
[viii]
Poole, “Give Us Our Eleven Days,” pp.131-137.
[ix]
See, for example, Daniel Boorstin, The Americans: The Colonial Experience
(New York, 1958).
[x]
Smith, “Culture, Commerce, and Calendar Reform,” pp.561-562.
[xi]
Ibid., p.562; Boston News-Letter, September 14, 1752.
[xii]
William Sumner Jenkins, ed., Records of the States of the United States
of American; a Microfilm Compilation (Washington, D.C., 1949), Mass., B
2b, reel 2, 1742-1774, session laws, May sess., 1752, page 369.
[xiii]
Generally, see Smith, “Culture, Commerce, and Calendar Reform,” p.566,
and for exceptions, see p. 567. To
this day, some federal agencies use a remnant of the Julian calendar to
begin their financial year. Plainly,
though, they operate principally on the Gregorian calendar.
[xv]
Ibid., p.574; Mark M. Smith, “Remembering Mary, Shaping Revolt:
Reconsidering the Stono Rebellion,” Journal of Southern History
LXVII (August 2001), pp. 513-34
[xvi]
Smith, “Culture,
Commerce, and Calendar Reform,” p.575.
[xviii]
Carlene Stephens, On Time: How America Has Learned to Live by the Clock
(Boston, 2002), p.102. Generally,
see Michael O’Malley, Keeping Watch: A History of American Time
(New York, 1990).
[xix]
See Mark M. Smith, Mastered by the Clock: Time, Slavery, and Freedom in
the America South (Chapel Hill, 1997), p.83.
[xx]
Stephens, On Time, pp. 100-101; Carlene E. Stephens, “The Most
Reliable Time: William Bond, the New England Railroads, and Time Awareness
in 19th-Century America,” Technology and Culture 30
(January 1989), pp. 16-21.
[xxi]
Ian R. Bartky, The Adoption of Standard Time,” Technology and Culture,
30 (January 1990), pp.25-56; Ian R. Bartky, Selling the True Time:
Nineteenth-Century Timekeeping in America (Stanford, 2000).
[xxii]
O’Malley, Keeping Watch, p. 111; Bartky, “Adoption of Standard
Time,” p.49. Allen’s time
zones were replaced in 1918, courtesy of the federal government.
Although the federal zones—the same ones used today—were
different they were indebted to Allen’s work.
[xxiii]
Bartky, “Adoption of Standard Time,” p. 26.
[xxiv]
Smith, Mastered by the Clock, pp.178-183.
[xxv]
O’Malley, Keeping Watch, pp.135, 139.
[xxvi]
Smith, Mastered by the Clock, pp. 182-184.
[xxvii]
See, for example, David S. Roediger, “Time, Republicanism, and Merchant
Capitalism: Consciousness of Hours before 1830,” in David Roediger and
Philip S. Foner, eds., Our Own Time: A History of Hours before 1830
(London, 1989), pp.1-19; David Brody, “Time and Work during Early American
Industrialization,” Labor History, 30 (winter 19189), pp.5-46; Paul
B. Hensley, “Time, Work, and Social Context in New England,” New
England Quarterly, 65 (December 1992), pp.531-559; Smith, Mastered by
the Clock.
[xxviii]
For a full discussion of this important topic, see Alexis McCrossen, Holy
Day, Holiday: The American Sunday (Ithaca, 2000).
--------------------------------------
>>>>进入论坛提问、发表评论
版权声明:本文(包括文字和图片)经中国民俗学会授权,未经许可,其他媒体(含已经获得常规新闻转载授权的网站)不得转载、节选、抄袭,违者将被追究法律责任。
责编:郭翠潇 来源:CCTV.com
|